Monetary policy committees, learning and communication /

Saved in:
Bibliographic Details
Author / Creator:Weber, Anke, 1981- author.
Imprint:[Washington, D.C.] : International Monetary Fund, ©2010.
Description:1 online resource (41 pages) : color illustrations
Language:English
Series:IMF working paper ; WP/10/85
IMF working paper ; WP/10/85.
Subject:
Format: E-Resource Book
URL for this record:http://pi.lib.uchicago.edu/1001/cat/bib/12499735
Hidden Bibliographic Details
Other authors / contributors:International Monetary Fund. Middle East and Central Asia Department, issuing body.
ISBN:128355240X
9781283552400
9781452751054
1452751056
Notes:Includes bibliographical references.
Print version record.
Summary:This paper considers optimal communication by monetary policy committees in a model of imperfect knowledge and learning. The main policy implications are that there may be costs to central bank communication if the public is perpetually learning about the committee's decision-making process and policy preferences. When committee members have heterogeneous policy preferences, welfare is greater under majority voting than under consensus decision-making. Furthermore, central bank communication under majority voting is more likely to be beneficial in this case. It is also shown that a chairman with stable policy preferences who carries significant weight in the monetary policy decision-making process is welfare enhancing.
Other form:Print version: Weber, Anke. Monetary Policy Committees, Learning, and Communication. Washington : International Monetary Fund, ©2010 9781451982633
Table of Contents:
  • Cover Page; Title Page; Copyright Page; Contents; I. Introduction; II. The Model; A. General Setup; B. Uncertainty About The Central Bank's Preferences; III. Monetary Policy Committee Decision-Making; A. The Preferences of Committee Members; B. Timing; C. The Policy Decision; C.1. Decision-making by consensus; C.2. Individualistic decision-making; IV. The Private Sector; A. Complete Opacity by Committee Members; B. Voting records and policy minutes published; C. Imperfect Communication of Preferences; C.1. No uncertainty about the precision of public information.
  • C.2. Imperfect knowledge of the precision of public informationV. Results; A. Perfect Knowledge Benchmark; B. Private Sector Imperfect Knowledge; B.1. Voting records and policy minutes are published; B.2. A chairman with added influence; B.3. Voting records and speeches are published; VI. Conclusion; Appendix; 1. RMSE of the public under averaging and voting: homogeneous policymakers; 2. RMSE of the public under averaging and voting: heterogeneous policymakers; 3. RMSE of the public with heterogeneous policymakers for different constant gains.
  • 4. RMSE of the public with homogeneous policymakers for different constant gains5. RMSE of the public under consensus with special influence of the chairman; 6. RMSE of the public under majority voting with special influence of the chairman; 7. RMSE of the public under majority voting with imperfect knowledge of precision of public information; Sensitivity Analysis; 1. Private sector RMSEs, preferences less persistent than in benchmark case; 2. Private sector RMSEs, preferences more persistent than in benchmark case.
  • 3. Private sector RMSEs, complete opacity, different persistence of members' preferences4. Effects of changing the variance of the noise in the preference aggregation equation; 5. Effects of varying N, heterogeneous members; 6. Effects of varying N, homogeneous members; 7. Private sector RMSEs, different variances of committee members' preferences; 8. Complete opacity, different variances of committee members' preferences; References; Footnotes.